Reflections on Trade: Part II

Reflections on Trade: Part II

In this multi-part report, we offer several reflections on trade that we hope can provide some insight into how to use macroeconomics to judge the veracity of certain claims. In Part I, we laid out the basic macroeconomics of trade. This week, in Part II, we will discuss the impact of exchange rates and examine the two models of economic development, the “Japan Model”1 and the “American Model.”2

The Japan Model of development calls for policies that drive up household saving. This is usually done through financial repression and wage suppression. This model is designed to provide cheap investment funds to build up the productive capacity of the country.

In contrast, the American Model of development relies on foreign investment. In this arrangement, the trade deficit is an import of foreign saving for investment.

As a review from Part I of our report, the following saving identity means that the private investment/savings balance (I-S) plus the public spending balance (Govt-Taxes) is equal to the trade account, M-X (Imports less Exports).

(M - X) = (I - S) + (G - Tx)

If a nation’s saving equals its investment and it runs a balanced fiscal budget, then it will run a balanced trade account. It doesn’t matter what the exchange rate is or what trade policy is in place; if the private and public sector balances, there will also be balanced trade.

Can a nation prevent a trade deficit through protectionism?
Yes, but the same identity described above is still in place. It is often believed that trade restrictions affect only the foreign saving part of the saving identity. However, because the identity is like a balance sheet, it actually must balance the other parts of the identity as well. Let’s assume a nation runs the Japan Model but the rest of the world won’t accept the exports. Investment, in the form of unwanted inventory, will rise, absorbing the excess saving. The unwanted inventory will have a negative impact on the economy using the Japan Model. This could include deflation as the excess inventory lowers prices, unemployment which reduces consumption and saving or rising fiscal deficits as the imbalanced nation tries to maintain the level of GDP.

Is there a cost to the nation deploying trade protection? Although nothing in that nation becomes unbalanced, there is the opportunity cost of not having cheaper imports available. Thus, it would likely lead to higher price levels that would not otherwise occur and lower prices in the nation using the Japan Model.