How Much Can Clients Spend in Retirement? A Test of the Two Most Prominent Approaches

In my last article, I described research-based innovations for variable withdrawal strategies from retirement portfolios. In this article, I put Jonathan Guyton’s decision rules and David Blanchett’s simplified withdrawal formula to the test. I simulate the income and remaining wealth generated with these two strategies using different underlying Monte Carlo assumptions. These results provide planners with a better understanding about the potential spending paths generated by these different approaches, and they also suggest where further improvements can be made with regard to designing variable retirement withdrawal strategies.

Brief overview of the spending strategies

My last article explained two of the key research-based variable retirement withdrawal frameworks: Jonathan Guyton’s and Dave Blanchett’s. Here’s a brief refresher.

Guyton’s decision rules have been popular with advisors for the past 10 years, providing a guide for increasing initial retirement spending on the condition that future spending may not always increase with inflation and may need to be cut when markets underperform. He proposed three decision rules:

  • Withdrawal rule, which increases withdrawals for inflation if the portfolio experienced a positive total return in the previous year.
  • Capital preservation rule, which reduces real spending by 10% if the year’s current withdrawal rate grows 20% above its initial level.
  • Prosperity rule, which increases real spending by 10% if the current withdrawal rate fell by at least 20% below its initial level.

Though it will not be part of my simulations, he also included a portfolio management rule, which focuses on how the investment portfolio is drawn down and rebalanced between different assets.

The second framework I simulate has a long lineage culminating in Blanchett’s development of a simple formula to update sustainable withdrawal rates on a year-by-year basis, which he described in a September 2013 Journal of Financial Planningarticle. Whereas Guyton’s decision rules generally call for inflation-adjusted spending to continue unless certain conditions are met, Blanchett’s formula provides a new withdrawal rate to use with remaining financial assets for each year of retirement. This creates a more volatile spending path. Advisors input four variables to determine an optimal withdrawal rate for each year of retirement: asset allocation, the remaining retirement time horizon, the targeted probability of success and an alpha term that reflects portfolio over- or underperformance relative to the built-in capital market expectations.

As this is a dynamic withdrawal model, Blanchett found that the optimal retirement horizon is the client’s median remaining life expectancy plus two years, and the optimal target probability of success is 80%. These parameters, when combined with the client’s asset allocation and capital-market expectations, provide a unique sustainable withdrawal rate for each year of retirement.

Capital-market expectations

To simulate spending and wealth with these withdrawal strategies, we must make a decision about capital-market expectations. This, in turn, suggests an appropriate initial withdrawal rate to begin retirement. In this regard, Blanchett’s system proves to be more flexible than Guyton’s. For illustration purposes, I will consider two sets of capital-market expectations.

Table 1 provides two sets of capital-market assumptions on which the simulations will be based (using a multivariate lognormal distribution).

The first set of expectations is based on Harold Evensky’s current inputs for MoneyGuidePro. These assumptions reflect lower stock and bond returns than implied by historical averages, which makes sense. Market conditions today suggest much less optimism about what may work for retirees. Interest rates are at historic lows and stock markets are overvalued based on metrics such as Shiller’s CAPE.

Nonetheless, many advisors are comfortable projecting forward the more optimistic historical experience of the U.S. For the second set of simulations, I used Ibbotson Associates' Stocks, Bonds, Bills, and Inflation (SBBI) data on total returns for U.S. financial markets since 1926. I used the S&P 500 index to represent the stock market and the intermediate-term U.S. government bond index to represent the bond market. In all cases, returns were calculated on an annual basis, withdrawals are taken at the beginning of each year and the portfolio was rebalanced annually to its target allocation.

Table 1

Capital-market assumptions for real returns based on current market conditions

Arithmetic

Means

Geometric Means

Standard Deviations

Correlation Coefficients

Stocks

Bonds

Inflation

Stocks

5.5%

3.4%

20.7%

1

0.1

-0.2

Bonds

1.8%

1.6%

6.5%

0.1

1

-0.6

Inflation

3.0%

2.9%

4.2%

-0.2

-0.6

1

Capital-market assumptions for real returns based on historical U.S. real returns and inflation data, 1926 – 2011

Arithmetic

Means

Geometric Means

Standard Deviations

Correlation Coefficients

Stocks

Bonds

Inflation

Stocks

8.6%

6.5%

20.7%

1

0.1

-0.2

Bonds

2.6%

2.3%

6.5%

0.1

1

-0.6

Inflation

3.1%

3.0%

4.2%

-0.2

-0.6

1

Figure 1 illustrates the withdrawal rates produced by Blanchett’s rule using his optimal parameters for time horizon and probability of success, an assumed 60%/40% stock/bond allocation and capital-market expectations equal to both historical averages and the less optimistic assumptions developed by Harold Evensky for MoneyGuidePro. Relative to Blanchett’s baseline capital-market expectations, the alpha term for the historical averages is 1.2%, and the alpha term for the current market conditions is -1.1%.

The important aspect with Blanchett’s method is that we can find a precise initial withdrawal rate to use given our capital-market expectations. In this case, with the 60/40 allocation, the initial withdrawal rate for the couple at age 65 is 3.8% with current market conditions and 4.9% with historical averages. As the remaining time horizon shortens with age, we can observe the increase in sustainable withdrawal rates at subsequent ages.

As well, when transitioning from age 80 to 81, the remaining life expectancy drops below 13. This, in turn, reduces the time horizon input term below 15, which triggers the shift to the alternative formula that only includes remaining time horizon. Capital-market expectations do not matter beyond that age, which is why the withdrawal rates are the same for both sets of assumptions after age 81. These are the withdrawal rates used in the subsequent simulations.

Figure 1

Meanwhile, Guyton’s analysis is implicitly based only on the historical averages available at the time of his research, with no direction about how an advisor should adjust initial withdrawal rates for different capital-market expectations. This forces users to make further assumptions about appropriate initial withdrawal rates. Based on historical averages, Guyton reported initial withdrawal rates for different time horizons (30 or 40 years), different asset allocations (ranging from 50% to 80% stocks), whether or not international assets are included in the asset-allocation mix, and different portfolio success rates (from 90% to 99%).

For instance, using U.S. assets with a 50/40/10 allocation to stocks/bonds/cash and a 40-year time horizon, Guyton recommended initial withdrawal rates ranging from 4.5% (with 99% confidence) to 5% (with 90% confidence). With a 65/25/10 asset allocation, the recommended initial withdrawal rates of between 5.2% (with 99% confidence) and 6% (with 90% confidence).

To the extent that these scenarios do not match what an advisor assumes, or what I am aiming to simulate, further judgment must be used to decide on an initial withdrawal rate. As one of the key aspects of Guyton’s decision rules is the idea that initial withdrawal rates can be higher than justified with constant inflation-adjusted spending, I assumed an initial withdrawal rate of 5.5% for both set of capital-market expectations.

This is an entirely subjective decision. When the initial withdrawal rate is higher, there will be a greater tendency for spending to trend downward over time.