Lacy Hunt: Keynes was Wrong (and Ricardo was Right)

Lacy Hunt

Underpinning the Obama administration’s economic policies is the work of John Maynard Keynes, the legendary British economist who called for large fiscal and monetary interventions to counter the Great Depression.

On this critical issue, Keynes was wrong, says Lacy Hunt.

The quantitative easing and fiscal stimulus efforts that, as a result, we see today around the globe are misguided, according to Hunt, who is an internationally renowned economist with Texas-based Hoisington Investment, an institutional fixed income manager.  He spoke on April 22 at the Strategic Investment Conference in San Diego, hosted by Altegris Investments and Millennium Wave Investments.

In addition to discussing the failings of Keynesian economics in the context of current monetary and fiscal policies, Lacy offered some forecasts for asset class returns.

Challenging conventional wisdom

Macroeconomic conventional wisdom currently has three major tenets, Hunt said:  first, current monetary and fiscal measures will stimulate economic growth and ultimately produce inflation; second, our debt problems are behind us, or at least should not deter policymakers from aggressive spending; and third, economic growth will cause the current account deficit to balloon, driving the dollar down, and inflation and interest rates up.

Citing his own firm’s research and that of prominent academics, Hunt challenged all three of those tenets.

Key to understanding Hunt’s arguments is a 2002 study he and his colleagues at Hoisington conducted.  It showed that the risk premium – the excess return of equities over risk-free Treasury Bills – has varied significantly over the last 140 years.  It averaged 3.5%, but for different 10-year intervals it ranged from -8.5% to 20%.

The researchers identified three explanations for the variation in the risk premium – one of which was previously unknown.  First, higher dividend yields, relative to the Treasury yield, produce greater risk premia.  During bull markets, the differential of dividend yields over Treasuries has been as high as 250 basis points, but today it is at negative 200 basis points.

“On the current income side, you are giving up quite a bit to be an equity investor,” he said.

Second, lower starting valuations, as measured by conventional P/E ratios, lead to higher risk premia.  The long-term P/E ratio, measured over the 140 years he studied, was 15, but today it is 24.  Hunt confirmed this finding using Tobin’s Q-ratio.  (He did not use Shiller’s P/E ratio, which normalizes earnings by averaging them over the trailing 10 years, since he would have had ten fewer years of data to analyze.)

The third and most critical factor, which was Hunt’s original contribution to the literature, is inflation.  Unlike the dividend yield and starting valuation, its value is not known in advance.  Higher inflation rates are good for equities, because firms have pricing power and bonds “get killed,” he said.   Inflation, he said, averaged 1.5% over the period he studied, so values above this produce higher-than-average risk premia.

With dividend yields and starting valuations at ominous levels for equities, what is the outlook for inflation?  Before discussing Hunt’s answer, let’s look at one aspect of his analysis that is critical to his thinking.